Distributism part 2

I missed a thing or two in my last post about Distributism, in order to conclude on a hard hit. I’ll sum the whole issue up in a few words, even though in my experience that’s the least effective way to make yourself clear; I have no idea why, since most of the time I wish long explanations were so condensed. To each his own, I suppose. Here’s the few words: The efficiency advantages of the giant corporations, and thus, their “natural” place in the market, is a false generalization. The reason for this is that the actual production methods that benefit from scale are relatively few, compared to those which only benefit from scale through regulatory and tax advantages. As a consequence, many, many huge organizations are really wasteful superstructure attached to a relatively small core of productive activity.

We are familiar to the comparisons between Distributist production and Capitalist production; the dozens of workshops versus the singular factory, the kitchen of every home versus the commercial kitchen, the five hundred farms of three acres each versus the single farm of fifteen hundred. But what if these aren’t the things we should be comparing? When we compare workshops and factories, we are not, almost by definition, comparing complete enterprises. We are comparing the productive cores of two enterprises, which is a very different thing when you consider the resources which are consumed in the other activities of the firm that owns that factory. Narrowing one’s focus to look exclusively at one of GM’s factories is to look exclusively at the most efficient part of the operation, and to disregard major forms of inefficiency, even those inherent even to the factory itself. Continue reading

Bitter, Free-Market Distributism [RAMBLES]

i used to wonder, when i stood in line at a permitting office (to understand what this is like for a Libertarian, try to imagine being a Puritan, somehow compelled to stand amid the crowd readying the sacrifice to Baal) why any eye of any official in the place remained unblackened. Or at least why such business was not conducted through bulletproof glass, to prevent every contractor or foreman from plucking every officer of interference from behind the counter and beating him senseless. Why was it possible for these officials, who had no more right to choose a wire gauge or outlet spacing for me than i have right to choose a wife for you, to get out three words of their interference or “correction” without having their interfering teeth kicked straight down their interfering throats? Why was i alone (or so nearly alone) in absolute rage?

The answer is startlingly simple. If i may speak for the worst kind of contractor, who has some skill in navigating the regulatory thicket, who knows when to pay fees, knows ahead of time which fees to pay, knows who to give donuts, knows whose boss to call…When he hears the official say, “That will be $387.00 non-refundable to check the plans for this shed.” He does not hear how unnecessarily difficult and costly his work is being made for him, he hears how impossible it is being made for others. $387.00 is a small price to pay for monopoly. His heart may well leap at the very absurdity of a regulatory requirement, as he laughs to himself, “Sure, a crew of illegal immigrants could do this job for half the price, but let’s see them perform an environmental impact study!” The more burdensome are the regulatory requirements, and the more unlike they are to production itself, the more viable competitors become non-viable.

‘”Here, I have some apples, would you like to buy them?” “Yes, thank you.” THAT’S HOW HARD IT SHOULD BE TO START A BUSINESS IN THIS COUNTRY.
-Ron Swanson

Continue reading

The formula for unhappiness

Let us address the problem of the real misery of vast numbers of men in the modern world. I’m talking about the prevalence of despair among citizens of modern societies, particularly male, but both wealthy and poor, successful, religious, nihilist, blue-collar, white-collar, healthy, unhealthy, really of all stripes. Unhappiness is a net drawing in all kinds, remarkably, all kinds who are secure against the miseries that attended the lives of their grandfathers. Why do suicide and alcoholism prevail to such a great extent in lands where starvation and exposure are all but eradicated? How is it that men have been saved from destruction, and ushered into a paradise of luxury and ease (relative to the hardships taken for granted a few generations ago) only to be cut down instead by an epidemic of self-destruction? How is it that every misfortune that afflicted our forefathers may be avoided, and a thousand satisfactions unavailable to them may be put before us, yet it is our generation’s lives that must be escaped in hard drink or shotgun blasts?

One idea would be that ease and luxury are unmanageable for men; that hardship is our natural environment, and we are lost without it, like salmon trying to fight their way upstream but finding no resisting current. This is to some extent true, in the sense that the satisfaction of contention is unique and essential to our life, but it is not unique to the struggles of our grandfathers, nor to the kind of hardships that are forced upon us by outside circumstance. Rather, in an individual life, we often see that escaping from a struggle with starvation actually opens the way for greater and more satisfying struggles, as of creative work or some personal, well-chosen mission. Depriving men of insecurity in their food supply or their shelter has not taken away from them the satisfaction of contending against obstacles, instead, it has set before them a choice of obstacles, whose overthrow will grant generally still greater satisfaction than the bare subsistence obtained through more basic labors in the face of a harsher world. By putting the struggles of Earth under men’s feet, we only place in their hands the struggles of the stars, if struggle is the desire of their hearts. Continue reading

Labor intensity

I was asked to explain something I asserted in How to mow the lawn, regarding the tendency of infinite investment growth to produce either unemployment or overwork or a mixture of the two. Now this is miles away from mainstream thought, and indeed I have not fully explored the speculation myself, but the basic concept is this: In the geometric growth model we have a population that grows at an ever-increasing (compounding) rate, and we attempt to overcome the ever-increasing needs of that populace through ever-increasing production. We take advantage of the compounding nature of economic growth to make sure it follows the same pattern as population, by continually investing a portion of our output in improving our ability to produce. This is really the basis of economic growth at all: Rather than putting 100% of our abilities towards making what we consume today, we dedicate say, 10% to improved machines and methods, which will make tomorrow’s production more abundant than today’s. By partially restraining our appetite for consumption and properly directing what we have saved into real improvement of means, we will enable ourselves to produce more. If we repeat this process each year or each generation, we can expect that next year (since we have increased our productive capacity) the 10% of our output which we invest is a bigger total investment than was this year’s. To take Keynes’s metaphor, we are eating a smaller portion of the pie, in order to make the pie grow larger, and by continuing in this practice, we can expect that the pie eventually becomes so large that the portion which we consume is actually larger than the entire pie with which we started. By investing a roughly fixed percentage of each year’s output in improving next year’s methods, we create an economy of compounding growth.

So once this has been achieved (a fixed practice of continuous, substantial investment) we have on the chart two geometric curves, continually growing ever steeper according to their rate of growth, and as long as our level of investment is sufficiently high, the curve on top will forever be production, while population is always a little shallower, a little lower, and always falling a little behind. In fact, the whole idea is that production must grow faster than does population so that quality of life may continuously improve. If the curves are actually parallel (the rate of growth in production and population are identical) quality of life must actually decline in the sense that the per-capita production is actually declining. This is reflected visually in the fact that the curves always stay the same vertical distance apart, but the that distance becomes more and more insignificant compared the enormity of the totals. What I’m getting at is that the growth of production must be on a trajectory to pull ahead of population, not track it, for the outcome to seem desirable. Per-capita production must increase (obviously) to achieve our goal of appreciable prosperity. If population is to grow on an infinite compounding course, production simply must compound even more aggressively to satisfy this.

[None of the above is inevitable. What I am saying is merely that given the goals of an infinite growth policy, the only apparent or real success of such a policy will consist of production growth accelerating ahead of population growth. This may not be possible, the investments may yield declining returns, production may be misallocated, production growth may hit absolute limits, etc. I merely claim that the infinite growth policy, if it ever succeeds or appears to succeed, will inevitably involve this: The rate of growth in production must exceed the rate of growth in population, because per-capita production must continually increase in order for economic policy to be of visible benefit to the consumer. Each generation must be richer, and not merely larger at the same level of wealth, for the public to view policy as a success.]

Along with the Austrians, I don’t approve of the use of mathematics to attempt to describe human action, but since I’m illustrating a concept of which I don’t approve, I’m going to include some graphs to illustrate what I’m getting at.MalthusHere we have the Malthusian view of the relationship between population and output (production), population being the red line, and projected output being the blue line. Their crossing represents the Malthusian “crisis point,” where population growth overtakes the limits of production, and scarcity and starvation take over. In this vision, the red line would not actually continue up as projected, but instead the population would be limited by the crisis, through famine and other destructive events resulting from the failure of the economy to provide for the vast numbers of people.

Continue reading

Conceptual brief: The Malthusian Doom

The Malthusian Doom is really problem number one in the study of Economics; not unemployment or The Great Depression or Stagflation. The problem comes in two or three different flavors, the most basic being the simple observation that population has a tendency to compound, and grow in a geometric pattern, while production of necessities has no such tendency and so grows more or less linearly. If a population is growing, its growth tends to actually accelerate, simply because if each couple produces an average of 2.5 children (for example), the following generation is larger, and so the following round of 2.5 children per couple is applied to a larger number of couples, and so the growth is compounded each generation. The danger of this is that eventually such acceleration must cause population to overrun the production of necessities, and starvation begin to hit.

That is the most basic version, in fact I heard it elementary school. In that description, the crisis point seems to be projected way off in the future somewhere. A subtler version of the same problem is to suggest (during the bad times this is sometimes suggested) that we have already hit the crisis point, and that the level of economic hardship in the world is a consequence of population being too great. The implication of this conception of the Malthusian Doom is that we are witnessing population straining to grow higher but being held back by scarcity. This implies that any effort to reduce the scarcity will fail to improve quality of life, but will succeed in increasing population. If a million more bushels of wheat are produced, they will not, in this vision, reduce hunger at all because more mouths will simply be produced to consume that wheat, and we’ll be right back where we started.

To me, the most interesting thing about the Malthusian Doom is how wrong it is about everything. Population does not necessarily grow geometrically; production does not necessarily or even generally grow linearly. The revelation that economic growth is a compounding phenomenon has been a great ray of hope to economists, but it has long been known that procreation is a voluntary function and not bound to behave in any particular way, especially a self-destructive and counter-incentive way. The stabilizing or even declining populations of modern societies unaffected by starvation simply makes empirically obvious GK Chesterton’s remark on Malthus in 1927: “Nothing depending on the human will can proceed by geometrical progression, and population certainly does not proceed by anything of the sort.”

How to mow the lawn

So there’s a story about post-Soviet Russia, of a tourist looking over at some urban green space being landscaped and seeing about ten guys with weed-whackers, laboriously cutting the grass. He asks why it isn’t one man, pushing a gas lawnmower that barely costs more than one of the tools currently in use, getting the job done faster and cheaper. “Mumble mumble…EMPLOYMENT!” comes the answer. The men’s employer is paying ten paychecks instead of one, because it is somebody’s goal (probably a policy goal) to increase paychecks. In effect, the use of the wrong tool for the job is here a welfare program.

And here we are, right in the teeth of an apparent paradox that absolutely confounds an unfortunate number of people. Because “Unemployment,” is the most immediately observed economic evil, make-work measures of this kind that actually discard productivity, are regarded as helpful economic treatments. The Free Market guys obviously mock this, saying, “Well, if it’s that easy to solve our economic problems, why not shut down the power plants and put everything back on muscle power? If retarding the use of productive technology is a net gain, then all invention and economic growth must be an economic evil, while stagnation and destruction are a good.” Work productivity can be reduced indefinitely, and very easily, through the breaking of tools, the forgetting of skills, through mismanagement, waste, and laziness; but what fool would call these economic positives? Continue reading